Inevitable Negative Consequence of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine

Introduction

The “Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine” often stands at the crossroads between corporate protectionism and individual rights in employment law. At least on the outset, the doctrine appears to be necessary to protect proprietary information from abuse through the movability of employees into competing companies. However, on closer inspection, it reflects an undesirable picture: the doctrine works not only a rewriting of employment agreements but also threatens basic rights and fair competition in the labor market.

The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine, if applied or over-applied incorrectly, has potentially expansive consequences with exceedingly negative effects on employees. To be able to communicate its core issues – impact on employees, impact on employers, and more importantly how it might squeeze the very principles of innovation and mobility in a healthy economy – the doctrine needs explanation.

What is the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine?

The doctrine of inevitable disclosure allows a court to enjoin the working of a departing employee on behalf of a competitor if the court determines it will inevitably disclose trade secrets or other confidential information from the former employer. Proof of actual wrongdoing is not necessary for this doctrine. Rather, it operates on the potentiality for disclosure—essentially the idea that if an employee moves to a competing firm, he or she will almost certainly disclose sensitive information, either intentionally or unwittingly.

Its most critical objection to the doctrine is that it is most commonly used through preliminary injunction, or a legal tool courts use to keep things as they are when the case is ongoing. It seems like a preventive measure, but it may have a grave consequence for the employee.

inevitable

Problem in Preliminary Injunctions: Winning Before the Case is Won

A preliminary injunction based on Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine usually is issued at least preliminarily premised on a finding of potential harm rather than wrongdoing. The employer has to prove that the employee has already misused trade secrets, but she might.

This way, the employer wins the case without waiting for its determination. For example, an employee might be barred from taking a new job because a court thinks that employee might reveal sensitive information. A case can take months or years to reach a final decision, and in this time, the employee is unable to work for another employer or further their career. In many instances, the waiting period effectively terminates the employee’s career advance even if the case is subsequently won.

And what is left for the employee? The employee suffers significant financial and professional losses without any proof that they’ve done anything wrong, while the employer gets what amounts to a non-compete agreement without having negotiated or paid for it.

The Judicial Rewriting of Two Employment Agreements

Another problem with the inevitable disclosure doctrine is that it leads to the judicial rewriting of not one but two employment agreements.

  1. Original Employment Contract

The first agreement that is modified is that of the employee and their original employer. When a court grants an injunction that prevents an employee from working for a competitor, it essentially adds a non-compete clause to the original employment contract-terms which the employee did not negotiate or agree to. The employer benefits instead with restrictions for which they do not have to pay. Courts, by definition, impose conditions on employees whom they never agreed to; they limit their professional autonomy without anything going back to the employer.

  1. The Contemplated Employment Contract

The second contract in need of a rewrite is that which exists between the employee and their contemplated new employer. An injunction, upon its issuance, subjects any previous negotiations between the employee and the new employer to ravage. The new employer may have agreed to employ the employee on certain conditions in anticipation of acquiring strengths developed from the previous job. However, the injunction negates all these discussions and prevents the employee either from assuming the role totally or at least the significant aspects of it. This leaves the employee without bargaining power and subsequently with no influence over his career trajectory.

In this regard, the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine effectively imposes conditions on employment both in the past and in the future without giving the employee any meaningful opportunity to participate.

Effects on Labor Market and Employment Mobility

The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine injects quite uncertain and unpredictable uncertainty into the labor market. Employees can never know whether future employment might be foreclosed based upon the doctrine’s broad applicability. The mere threat of an injunction may chill talented professionals from pursuing alternative opportunities, especially in industries in which trade secrets and proprietary information are most highly valued.

Furthermore, the rule is squarely at odds with the well-settled “Employment at Will” rule. The employment-at-will doctrine authorized both employers and employees to terminate the employment relationship at will for any reason-including bad cause-unless they violated public policy. That freedom is basic to the mobility of a labor market, allowing employees to seek better bargains and employers to adapt to changed business conditions.

This freedom can be watered down with the aid of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine, in a manner by which employees are denied new jobs. In theory, an employee may keep the right to leave his job, but practically, a new position is denied based on the threat of inevitable disclosure; that is another burden on employees who want to change jobs at the risk of being prevented from so doing through the legalistic maneuvers of the former employer.

Employment at Will vs. Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine

This, therefore, brings out stark contrast between the two Doctrines: the Employment at Will Doctrine is bound to push labor market flexibility and flexibility in the ability of workers to change jobs as they please. The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine, on the other hand, constrains constraints tending to punish the employee for seeking alternative means of employment. If right to change jobs turns into an illusion with an injunction preventing an employee from exercising his or her accumulated skills and experience at a new company, that would be a very, very bad consequence.

The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine prevents employment mobility and chills labor market friction, which does not serve an important end. It injures employees who may end up doing less ambitious or more understaffed work than they deserve and companies that are prevented from hiring well-salaried employees because of constrictions under the law. This eventually leads to decreased competition, low innovation, and costs to consumers.

Conclusion: The Chill on Competition

The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine has a chilling effect on competition and innovation because it threatens too much, and is thus likely to stifle a good deal of properly competitive activity. It chills workers, former employers, and prospective employers of workers, threatening them all with litigation that is costly and uncertain. Workers lose opportunities; the economy suffers as competition declines and perhaps leads to higher consumer prices and less innovation.

While protecting trade secrets and encouraging business fair play are necessary, courts should tread on this doctrine with extra caution, as it puts weighty burdens of proof on the party seeking to stop the future disclosure. Indeed, before the injunction is granted, it must be seen that there is concrete evidence of actual harm if the employee continues along a course of action that would eventually lead to disclosure. Otherwise, the doctrine risks causing more harm than good-in other words, penalizing an employee for looking for better opportunities and not walking according to the tenets of a competitive market.

At its core, society benefits from a labor market that encourages competition, innovation, and mobility. The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine, as currently designed, poses a significant threat to these values. Courts should treat this balancing act with great care so the protection of trade secrets is not at the expense of workers’ rights or the general economy. An injunction applied in the wrong place may result in grave injustice and more than often is visited upon the worker’s doorstep.

Author: Kaustubh Kumar, in case of any queries please contact/write back to us via email to chhavi@khuranaandkhurana.com or at  Khurana & Khurana, Advocates and IP Attorney.

REFERENCES

  1. John H. Matheson, Employee Beware: The Irreparable Damage of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine, 10 Loy. Consumer L. Rev. 145 (1998).
  2. Lumen Human resource Management, Module 12: Employee Rights and Responsibilities, Lumen (November 12, 2021, 10:30 AM), https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-humanresourcesmgmt/chapter/employment-at-will-doctrine/.
  3. Jessica Lee, The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine: Safeguarding the Privacy of Trade Secrets, Colorado Lawyer 17 (2004).
  4. Nathan Hamler, The Impending Merger of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine and Negative Trade Secrets: Is Trade Secrets Law Headed in the Right Direction?, 25 J. Corp. L. 383, 388 (2000).

Leave a Reply

Categories

Archives

  • December 2024
  • November 2024
  • October 2024
  • September 2024
  • August 2024
  • July 2024
  • June 2024
  • May 2024
  • April 2024
  • March 2024
  • February 2024
  • January 2024
  • December 2023
  • November 2023
  • October 2023
  • September 2023
  • August 2023
  • July 2023
  • June 2023
  • May 2023
  • April 2023
  • March 2023
  • February 2023
  • January 2023
  • December 2022
  • November 2022
  • October 2022
  • September 2022
  • August 2022
  • July 2022
  • June 2022
  • May 2022
  • April 2022
  • March 2022
  • February 2022
  • January 2022
  • December 2021
  • November 2021
  • October 2021
  • September 2021
  • August 2021
  • July 2021
  • June 2021
  • May 2021
  • April 2021
  • March 2021
  • February 2021
  • January 2021
  • December 2020
  • November 2020
  • October 2020
  • September 2020
  • August 2020
  • July 2020
  • June 2020
  • May 2020
  • April 2020
  • March 2020
  • February 2020
  • January 2020
  • December 2019
  • November 2019
  • October 2019
  • September 2019
  • August 2019
  • July 2019
  • June 2019
  • May 2019
  • April 2019
  • March 2019
  • February 2019
  • January 2019
  • December 2018
  • November 2018
  • October 2018
  • September 2018
  • August 2018
  • July 2018
  • June 2018
  • May 2018
  • April 2018
  • March 2018
  • February 2018
  • January 2018
  • December 2017
  • November 2017
  • September 2017
  • August 2017
  • July 2017
  • June 2017
  • May 2017
  • April 2017
  • March 2017
  • February 2017
  • January 2017
  • December 2016
  • November 2016
  • October 2016
  • September 2016
  • August 2016
  • July 2016
  • June 2016
  • May 2016
  • April 2016
  • March 2016
  • February 2016
  • January 2016
  • December 2015
  • November 2015
  • October 2015
  • September 2015
  • August 2015
  • July 2015
  • June 2015
  • May 2015
  • April 2015
  • March 2015
  • February 2015
  • January 2015
  • December 2014
  • November 2014
  • October 2014
  • September 2014
  • August 2014
  • July 2014
  • May 2014
  • April 2014
  • March 2014
  • February 2014
  • January 2014
  • December 2013
  • November 2013
  • October 2013
  • September 2013
  • August 2013
  • July 2013
  • June 2013
  • May 2013
  • April 2013
  • March 2013
  • February 2013
  • January 2013
  • December 2012
  • November 2012
  • September 2012
  • August 2012
  • July 2012
  • June 2012
  • May 2012
  • April 2012
  • March 2012
  • February 2012
  • January 2012
  • December 2011
  • November 2011
  • October 2011
  • September 2011
  • August 2011
  • July 2011
  • June 2011
  • May 2011
  • April 2011
  • February 2011
  • January 2011
  • December 2010
  • September 2010
  • July 2010
  • June 2010
  • May 2010
  • April 2010